On land ownership and tenancy
The private owner's interest turns 'sand into gold' was
the opinion held by one extreme, whereas according to the
socialistic viewpoint, private ownership of the production
factor land leads to exploitation and should be abolished.
It would be possible to prove both arguments empirically.
In the course of time, a more detailed and less ideological
analysis led to a more differentiated point of view. Property,
including property in land, is a basic element of the economic
order. Its clear definition, uniform for all men, is a basic
requirement and usually regulated in the constitution.
It is necessary to differentiate between property and private
property in land. This is one possibility that has been developing
historically and culture specifically. It gives the owner
security and provides a planning horizon and incentives and,
thus, allows investment. In some societies, it is an important
basis for credit to the farmers. In many cultures it has led
to long-lasting and remarkable progress in agricultural development.
In not a few cases, however, some of the owners became too
successful and exploited others, resulting in dependency and
poverty on the part of the masses.
The option of state or socialistic ownership of the land
produced negative results, especially respecting production,
and in particular due to 'human failure'. Its transformation
in recent years has not been completed yet. So far it has
brought about a certain opening of the market and its incentives,
however incomplete. Several countries have hesitated to introduce
private property in land. The process is still under debate
and is made difficult by the fact that the dismantling of
the collectives erodes the social security of all the people
belonging to them. The same holds true with respect to the
deteriorating communal organization of land rights in parts
of Africa, and to a lesser degree in Asia and Latin America
as well. In the regard, the increasing interference of the
state leads to a weakening of the indigenous institutions
and traditional regulation of land rights.
Important changes took place in the field of the ownership
of usufruct rights. At the beginning, the prohibition of tenancy
was considered in several countries to be the right answer
to the lasting difficulties in regulating tenancy in a way
which would grant justice to both partners. In other countries,
policies in favour of the lessees worked in the direction
of an abolition of tenancy. It proved impossible, however,
to strictly enforce these laws because there are too many
possibilities to circumvent them. Within the course of time,
changing framework conditions had their impact and led to
rethinking. On the one hand, many landlords dismissed their
tenants after the 'green revolution' and used the potential
to make money by cultivation on centralized farms. On the
other hand, urbanization and the transition to multiple employment
with continually decreasing farm sizes require easy possibilities
allowing the temporary transfer of usufruct rights, i.e.,
tenancy. Some governments created new models such as the 'entrustment
of land' which upon a closer look are just synonyms for the
illegal tenancy. In Africa, there has been an emergence of
tenancy relations with certain parallels.
This change was furthered by an incomplete but widespread
change in the characteristics of the lessees. Today it is
less the large landowner who rents out land, but rather increasingly
the smallholder because he wants to give up farming. This
means that it is more often a neighbour, a relative, or at
least a person of a similar status. This change has by all
means not done away with all of the problems involved in the
lessee-tenant relation, but it has definitely had an impact
on the forms and kind of tenancy and relationship.
The most recent impact on tenancy originated in Vietnam and
some other transformation countries which maintained ownership
of land in the hands of the state. In this case, land was
leased to cultivators for at first 6 years, and later the
usufruct rights were granted for 20 or 50 years, with an option
for renewal, and were made inheritable and transferable. This
provided a level of security and a horizon for planning and
investment similar to that found in private ownership of land
and functioned as a strong incentive respecting production.
This system, which resembles the historic tradition in many
countries of the world, is still rather new, but it should
be watched carefully. It might prove to be a model for other
countries.
|